Download PDF | Beatrice Forbes Manz - Power, politics and religion in Timurid Iran-Cambridge University Press (2007).
336 Pages
Power, Politics and Religion in Timurid Iran Beatrice Forbes Manz uses the history of Iran under the Timurid ruler Shahrukh (1409–47) to analyze the relationship between government and society in the medieval Middle East. She provides a rich portrait of Iranian society over an exceptionally broad spectrum – the dynasty and its servitors, city elites and provincial rulers, and the religious classes, both ulama and Sufi. The work addresses two issues central to premodern Middle Eastern history: how a government without the monopoly of force controlled a heterogeneous society, and how a society with diffuse power structures remained stable over long periods. Written for an audience of students as well as scholars, this book provides the first broad analysis of political dynamics in late medieval Iran and challenges much received wisdom about civil and military power, the relationship of government to society, and the interaction of religious figures with the ruling class.
BEATRICE FORBES MANZ is Associate Professor of History at Tufts University, Massachusetts. Her previous publications include The Rise and Fall of Tamerlane (1989) and, as editor, Studies on Chinese and Islamic Central Asia (1995).
Preface
I have profited from the support of several institutions while writing this book. A fellowship from the American Research Institute in Turkey in 1990 allowed me to begin research in the libraries of Istanbul. In the summer of 1996 I spent two months in Tashkent, Bukhara and Samarqand on a Tufts Faculty Research award. Grants from the American Council of Learned Societies and the National Endowment for the Humanities in 1991–92 and a National Council for Eurasian and East European Research Fellowship for the calendar year 1999 allowed me to take leave from teaching. Finally, in 2003–04 a membership at the School of Historical Studies, Institute for Advanced Studies, together with an American Council of Learned Societies fellowship and a Tufts Faculty Research award allowed me to finish the manuscript while beginning my next project.
To all of these institutions I want to express my heartfelt thanks. A number of individuals have also provided valuable help. Professor Bert Fragner generously facilitated a semester spent at the University in Bamberg, in spring, 1993, which provided a peaceful place to work and an introduction to several colleagues who continue to help and inspire. Leonard Lewisohn lent me his unpublished dissertation and answered a number of important questions for me. Several colleagues have read parts of the manuscript and offered valuable advice; I want to thank in particular Devin Deweese, Jo-Ann Gross, Ahmet Karamustafa, Robert McChesney, David Morgan, Johannes Pahlitsch and Jurgen Paul.
Finally, I want to express my gratitude to Hesna ¨ Ergun and Hande Deniz, for their invaluable help with the index and galleys. ¨ The work of two scholars in particular underlies much of what I have written here. The numerous articles of the late Jean Aubin provided an indispensable base and constant inspiration for me, as he has for anyone writing on this and related periods. Over the course of his long career, Professor Iraj Afshar has collected and edited an extraordinary number of medieval sources, particularly the local histories crucial to the understanding of southern and central Iran. Without his work, the sections of the book on central and southern Iran could not have been written.
Note on usage
I have tried to make this book both useful for scholars and accessible to nonspecialists. My solution to the perennial problem of transcription is to use classical Arabic transcription for Arabic and Persian names and terms, but not for Turkic ones. Names of well-known cities are written with their common spelling, while less well-known ones are transcribed in classical fashion. Within the text I have omitted most diacriticals except for technical terms. In bibliographical references and the index to the book, full diacriticals are used. Dates are given first according to the Islamic calendar and then the Christian one.
Introduction
A scholar contemplating pre-modern government must experience a sense of wonder. How was it possible to keep control over an extensive region with so few of the tools that modern governments possess? The central administration rarely held a monopoly of force, and a message sent to the other end of the kingdom could require weeks or months to arrive. The population spoke a variety of languages and most were more firmly attached to local elites than they were to the central government. Tax collection was difficult, since both landowners and peasants attempted to thwart the process.
In the medieval Middle East, the challenge was particularly great, since there were few legal entities which provided society with a formal structure or regulated relationships among its separate parts. Furthermore its inhabitants included not only urban and agricultural populations but also large numbers of mountain peoples and nomads, some of whom inhabited regions almost inaccessible to government forces. Despite all this, governments did gain and hold power in the Middle East and society remained remarkably cohesive and resilient through numerous dynastic changes. This book is an examination of how the system worked: both how government retained control over society, and how society maintained its cohesion through periods of central rule and of internal disorder.
It is also a portrait of a particular place, time and dynasty: the place is Iran, the time the first half of the fifteenth century, and the dynasty is the Timurids, founded by the TurcoMongolian conqueror Temur, or Tamerlane (r. 1370–1405). I am examining ¨ in particular the reign of Tamerlane’s son Shahrukh who ruled from 1409 to 1447. The Timurid dynasty and its military followers came from outside the Middle East, spoke a language foreign to most of the population, and depended on an army that was consciously different from their Iranian subjects. At the same time they were Muslim, literate, and for the most part fluent in Persian. Many were landowners and cultural patrons who had much in common with their subjects, and particularly with the Persian elite who made up the class of city notables. Timurid rule depended on the superiority of nomad armies, but, like all other rulers, the Timurids required some form of consent from the population.
The relationship of government to society in the medieval Middle East is a slippery question. Here, as elsewhere, the ruler was the lynchpin of government, despite his inability to monopolize coercive force. He held an ambivalent position – above his followers and subjects, but also at their mercy. Because there was no fixed system of succession, the death of a ruler often unleashed a struggle. A serious illness commonly brought disorders within the realm and death could precipitate a free-for-all, bringing with it the destruction of crops and cities and the implementation of ruinous taxes. The Sufi shaykh Khwaja Ahrar told his disciples that his family had been preparing a feast to celebrate the shaving of his head on his first birthday, when they learned the news of Temur’s death in 1405.
They were too fright- ¨ ened to eat, and so emptied the cauldrons onto the ground and fled to hide in the mountains.1 The population’s panic was fully justified. The importance of the ruler to the system did not ensure respect to central government, the ruler’s possessions, or even to his corpse after death.2 Despite the fragility of central rule, the medieval Middle East was the locus of a stable and self-replicating society, which was based on personal ties rather than formal structures. The urban populations who depended most directly on central rule included separate and self-conscious groups: the religious classes, artisans, and merchants – none of them organized into legal corporate bodies with a fixed relationship to the ruler or the city. Major cities contained centrally appointed governors and garrison troops, but not in numbers large enough to dominate the area.
The towns from which the Timurids ruled their dominions were rather like an archipelago within a sea of semi-independent regions, over which control was a matter of luck, alliance and an occasional punitive expedition. Some major cities remained under their own leaders, as vassals of the higher power. All of the local rulers, of cities, mountain regions and tribes, had their own political programs. Nonetheless the economic system remained strong enough to make the Middle East one of the most powerful and prosperous regions of the world. I am not the first to attempt an analysis of the relationship between government and society in this area, and my study owes a great deal to those which have preceded it. Roy Mottahedeh’s classic study, Loyalty and Leadership in an Early Islamic Society, demonstrated the importance of social and ideological loyalties in forging the bonds which fostered order in early medieval Iran. As he showed, people created loyalties in predictable ways through oaths which bound them in relationships of clientage or military service.
Although such acquired loyalties did not survive the men who made them, they were often dictated or reinforced through loyalties of category based on a perception of shared self-interest among people of common family, lifestyle or profession. Almost from the beginning of Islamic history, there was a theoretical separation between the ruler and his subjects, considered necessary because only a ruler outside the groups making up society would be able to remain impartial and maintain a balance among them.
The dreams which connected the ruler to the supernatural, and made his rule a compact with God rather than with man, were one mark of the ruler’s separate status.3 More recently Jurgen Paul has presented an analysis of eastern Iran and ¨ Transoxiana up to the Mongol period emphasizing the economic and institutional aspects of government and society. He describes a division of tasks between local elites and the central government with a relationship mediated largely by the local notables and Sufi shaykhs, whose importance increased as the period progressed. What set the notables apart was their local base of power, which was independent of the central government. Both Mottahedeh and Paul stress the importance of individual loyalties to personal groupings and the ruler himself. Paul discusses a long period and suggests an increasing distance between government and society from the eleventh century, with the advent of nomad rulers who were less connected with agricultural and urban society.4 For the later period two scholars, Marshall G. S. Hodgson and Albert Hourani, put forward complementary theories of the relationship between government and society which have been widely accepted.
Hodgson outlined a dynamic which he called the ‘‘aqyan -amır system.’’ The landowning classes were drawn to the cities, where they exerted influence through clientship, in a social atmosphere imbued with the values of Islamic law. Order and security were assured by a garrison of military commanders – emirs – who were often foreign.5 Hourani described the politics among the city notables, drawn from these landowning classes and dominated, usually, by the ulama. Hourani showed that the city elite could control a significant part of city life and in times of government weakness or crisis they could take over governance of the city.6 Thus we see a separation between government and society with the city and its elite as the point of contact. Government and society were connected by a tacit contractual relation based on common interests in stability, the promotion of religion, and the protection of trade and agriculture. For the later period in particular, military matters are seen to be the domain of the government, largely removed from the general population. Since the central administration took limited responsibility for the daily life of the population, social cohesion is usually ascribed to the strength of social and kinship groups controlling the life of the individual.7
The basic schema drawn by Hourani and Hodgson has been elaborated by numerous specialized works over the last thirty years, particularly concerning the religious classes who made up the core of the city notables. In such studies, scholars draw conclusions about the general from the particular, and the choice of population studied is determined by the sources available. The middle period of Islamic history, from the Seljukid through the Mamluk and Timurid period, has provided most of the material for detailed analysis. For social history, biographical works are usually the most valuable source and studies of urban life and the activities of the ulama are most often based on material from the Mamluk Sultanate which produced rich historical literature, including voluminous biographical collections on the ulama. Studies on the composition and organization of the military have also depended heavily on the superior sources available from the Mamluk regions.8 For Iran and Central Asia, there is much less information on ulama but we have a fund of biographical literature on Sufi shaykhs.
These have strong influence over our views on Sufi society. A social history of the Middle East based on existing secondary studies is likely to depend on Mamluk material about cities and the ulama, but may favor Iranian material for Sufi circles. We should recognize however, that social norms in the two regions may not have been identical. While studies on individual communities can provide invaluable insight into social history, they do not fit together well to produce a composite picture of the dynamics of society as a whole. The literature of the medieval period divides society into classes and types of people, and separates out the history of each. Each genre of historical compilation preserves a different type of information, and thus provides a selected and homogenized picture of the people with which it deals; together the sources serve to emphasize the peculiarities of each group and the differences between them.
The picture thus presented of separate and distinct groups is misleading. Neither occupational nor kinship groups were mutually exclusive. Few people and certainly few families belonged to only one class or type; this is something we know and often acknowledge, but it is nonetheless difficult to write history in a way that fully incorporates our understanding. Furthermore, we must recognize that politics, even within a given milieu, rarely involved only internal personnel; people fighting over a common prize often reached outside their own group for allies. Just as no type of person was clearly defined and separated from others, there was no sphere of power controlled exclusively by one group of people. Rulers and military were important in the religious sphere and religious figures in the economic one. In Iran at least, the city classes, including both artisans and ulama, played an important role in regional military contests. The nomad and semi-nomad populations of mountain and steppe were connected not only to central and regional military powers, but also directly to city populations. Most studies have focused on institutions and on the practices they engendered. In this book I attempt to analyze the relationship between government and society primarily by examining the practice of politics, seeking the dynamics that kept people together within the groups they belonged to, and connected people of different associations. I am looking for the blurred edges of groups; for the overlaps among different types of organizations and classes of people. I have chosen to concentrate on a single defined period, the reign of Tamerlane’s son Shahrukh and the first years of the power struggle after his death.
The place is likewise limited to Iran and Central Asia, which were the central parts of Shahrukh’s domains. While the use of a limited time and region prevent me from drawing conclusions which can be confidently applied over a longer period, it does offer a number of advantages. First of all, it allows the use of a variety of interrelated sources, which make it possible to trace the activities of important people in different spheres. In this way, the action of an individual in one situation can be judged against accounts from different sources; we can discern secondary identities not mentioned in a single type of source. Secondly, it is possible in a detailed study to recognize the different affiliations contributing to the prestige of an individual or a family. I have tried to treat individuals not as representatives of particular groups but as independent actors, using whatever affiliations were available to them. I have done the same in the case of cities and provinces. Here again, there are advantages to a study which goes beyond the individual city but remains within a contained period. It is possible both to determine something of the common political structure in Iranian cities and to discern variations in political culture.
Likewise, in the case of provinces and regions, one can perceive a range of difference within the larger system. Examining a number of different Sufi affiliations, together with contemporary habits of shrine visitation, allows us to analyze the interaction among communities and to gauge their place and their role in society more fully than the study of one t.arıqa over time would allow. Moreover, the detailed analysis of a particular time and place permits the historian to check the actual against the ideal. The literature of the period is liberal in its explanations of approved attitudes and the narrative is shaped to reflect them. If motives for behavior are mentioned they will fit into the categories considered appropriate, and it is thus important to keep in mind that collective memory can distort both events and conventions to fit what are perceived as the rules of society. William Lancaster has analyzed the practice of manipulation in his discussion of genealogy among the Rwala Bedouin: As political and economic motives change with time, so the genealogy must change to accommodate changing assets and new options and so there is no true genealogy – truth is relative to the pragmatic needs of the group involved.
Thus a society that appears to be constrained by the past (for this is how we see genealogies) is in fact generating the very genealogy through which it ‘explains’ the present, and ... using that genealogy to generate the future.9 Many of our sources manipulate their material in similar ways, and while we cannot untangle relationships and motivation reliably, the use of a variety of different sources and the study of different groups does allow some correction to the picture provided. There are two major questions posed in this study: first, how a government retained power and fulfilled its function without a monopoly of force, and second, how society maintained its cohesion. The most common answer for the functioning of government has been that the preservation of order was worth the payment of taxes. The city populations who made up urban government thus had some common interests with the ruling group.10 Society was so frightened of disorder that any government was better than none at all, and should thus be obeyed; this maxim became a truism of premodern political thought.11 Had obedience been only passive, this explanation would be sufficient, but in Iran at least urban elites and semi-independent rulers were actively engaged in politics and military activity.
In examining the life of the cities, religious classes, and independent rulers, one sees a mass of people pursuing their interests with the tools they had at hand. Some further explanation is therefore needed. I have examined here not only the common interests which might persuade powerful, independent groups to collaborate with the government, but also the way in which their internal politics intersected with those of the central and provincial administrations. The other major issue I address is the cohesion of society, and here a central part of the discussion is the question of how to deal with the relationship of the individual to the group. When we learn that a person was a member of a given commonality, what does that tell us? If people saw themselves less as free individuals than as members of a group or community, then we must attempt to understand how a specific community affected the individual, what its internal politics were, and how it fit into society at large. We should not assume that because a group was an important factor in the life of its members it would command their full loyalty or achieve internal unity.
The history of any royal lineage demonstrates that blood ties can cause as much conflict as cooperation. The extended families central to pre-modern society also fostered internal rivalry; one can argue that the more benefits the extended family offers, the more likely it is that there will be strife within it. The central question, then, is how people coped with the constraints and possibilities of their society. Each group to which a person belonged offered both support and danger; one could hope to call on one’s fellows for help, but one was very likely to be competing with them for a common set of prizes. Alliances thus often went across recognized groups, both of birth and of training. The politics of the Timurid period was highly factional, with a dynamic made up of individuals with multiple loyalties, identities and rivalries. The multiplicity of obligation gave choice back to the individual person – anyone in a position of wealth or authority had to navigate among a variety of conflicting obligations and attachments. Thus, in the end, we must assume that the individual was a key player in this society, and not always a predictable one.
The place and the period The period I have chosen for this study is the early fifteenth century, and the dynasty that of the Timurids, who ruled Iran and Central Asia for much of the century. The founder of the dynasty was Temur, a Muslim Turk of ¨ Mongol descent who came to power in Samarqand in 1370 and spent most of his life in spectacularly successful conquest. He was succeeded by his son Shahrukh, whose reign, from 1409–47, is the focus of this study. Shahrukh was a cautious ruler who balanced the ideological and political forces of his time to consolidate control over a friable realm, and he was a man who fit the time he lived in. The fifteenth century offers us less sound and fury, and fewer outstanding personalities than the centuries which preceded and followed it. The major dynasties who controlled the Middle East after the Mongol conquests were already in power: the Ottomans in Anatolia and eastern Europe, the Mamluks in Syria and Egypt, the Timurids in Iran and Central Asia and the Delhi sultans in northern India. This was a period in which the changes of the past could be assimilated and newly won positions consolidated. One of the great watersheds in the history of the central Islamic lands was the Mongol invasion of the early thirteenth century.
The whole of the Middle East was affected by their rule, either directly or by example: their conquests and their rivalries became part of the political dynamic of the Middle East. After the death of Chinggis Khan in 1227, his empire was ruled by a supreme khan or khaghan and was divided into sections ruled by subordinate khans from the families of Chinggis Khan’s four sons by his chief wife. The western region stretching from the steppes north of the Black Sea to the Aral Sea and into Siberia was the inheritance of the eldest son, Jochi. The family of the second son, Chaghadai,12 held much of central Asia from Transoxiana through Turkistan and the Ili region. Chinggis’s third son Ogedei became ¨ supreme khan, but the personal area of his house lay outside Mongolia, in the Altai. The youngest son Tolui inherited Mongolia itself; his descendants succeeded in taking over the position of great khan, and then in founding a separate dynasty in Iran: the Ilkhanate. After the death of the great khan Mongke in 1259, no one member of Chinggis Khan’s family was able to ¨ achieve universal recognition as khaghan. Supreme power remained limited to the family of Chinggis Khan but each section of the empire was ruled as an independent state. By the mid-fourteenth century, the Mongol elites west of Mongolia had converted to Islam, and the Islamic and Mongol worlds had come to overlap. Despite its division, as an idea the Mongol Empire remained strong and the memory of Chinggis Khan retained a supreme place in political and cultural traditions. In the Middle East the Mongol conquest reinforced some old political traditions and introduced new ones. The elimination of the caliphate with the fall of Baghdad in 1258 created new possibilities for rulers within the Islamic world.
It became possible to claim full sovereign power within one area and to base one’s legitimacy on dynastic claims unrelated to the house of the Prophet. The first to take advantage of the new situation were the Mamluks in Egypt and Syria, who based their legitimacy in part on their resistance to the Mongols and their possession of a descendant of the qAbbasid dynasty whom they kept in Cairo as a titular caliph. Iran and Iraq were ruled by the Mongol Ilkhans. Mongol rule brought about an ethnographic change, with the division of the region into separate culture areas. The arrival of new nomads to occupy the pastures of the eastern regions displaced Turks who had entered with the Seljukid invasions of the eleventh century. This population had already begun to move into Anatolia, and Mongol pressure completed the Turkification of the region.
Mongol rule centered in Iran and did not extend beyond Iraq, thus creating a separation between these areas and the Arab cultural region of Egypt and the Levant controlled by the Mamluks. From this time on, the Middle East has retained the division into three major cultural zones, one primarily Arab, one primarily Iranian, and one primarily Turkic. In Iran and Central Asia the impact of Mongol rule was far-reaching. Throughout their realms, the Mongols introduced a period of experimentation.
In the realm of culture, science and daily life, they brought in changes of all sorts – new foods, new plants, new styles of art.13 In the political sphere, they brought in traditions from earlier steppe empires and from China. In the fifteenth century many Mongol administrative traditions were still in force. There were regional armies conscripted from the population and organized in decimal units, military governors – darughas – in many cities, and a TurcoMongolian military and court administration bearing Mongol titles. These two regions were part of the former Mongol Empire, just as they were part of the former caliphate. The high culture of Iran under the Mongols was influenced by its new ruling class, and by the end of the Mongol period Iran differed markedly from the Arab regions of Egypt and Syria in literary and visual culture. The Mongols employed many Iranian bureaucrats, and, at their court, Persian became the primary language of high culture.
In the visual arts they introduced significant Chinese influence and their rule oversaw the introduction of a new art form, the Persian miniature. By the Timurid period the Persian miniature was well established and buildings, decorated liberally in colored tiles, were very different from the Mamluk architecture which relied on stone for decoration. In the fourteenth century, as the descendants of Chinggis Khan began to lose power in some of the areas they controlled, a heady period of apparently unlimited opportunity arose. In China, an indigenous dynasty took control and pushed the Mongol ruling class back into the steppe. Towards the end of the century, the Chinggisid ruler Tokhtamish reunited much of the Jochid section of the Mongol realm and revived its claims to the Transcaucasus and Khorezm. In the west, the Ottomans under Bayazid I (r. 1389–1402), decisively entered the central Islamic lands and laid claim to the whole of Anatolia. The most spectacular career was that of Temur, who undertook a ¨ symbolic recreation of the Mongol Empire. He died in his eighties on his way to reconquer China, where Mongol government had been overthrown in 1368. While he was not descended from Chinggis Khan and thus could not claim supreme power for himself, he created a structure of Mongol legitimation by marrying into the Chinggisid house and ruling formally through a puppet khan descended from Chinggis. At the same time, Temur claimed ¨ supremacy in the Islamic world and crushed the Mamluk and Ottoman rulers who dared to assert equality. In explaining the justice of his conquests, he called on both the sharıqa and Mongol traditions. The great military engagements of Temur and his contemporaries gave way ¨ after his death, in 1405, to a period of more cautious rule within most of the Islamic lands. In both the Mamluk Sultanate and the Ottoman state the first task was to repair the ravages of Temur’s campaigns and to regain formal independence from the Timurid dynasty.
The level of ambition shown by Bayazid I was not appropriate for his immediate successors. For the Delhi Sultanate and the other Muslim dynasties of northern India, even independence was beyond reasonable expectations, and they continued as formal vassals of the Timurids to the end of Shahrukh’s reign.14 The Golden Horde of the Russian steppe could support local rulers in the Crimea or the Volga, but had lost control over the trade routes and much of their influence over the western steppe. Neither the Islamic nor the Turco-Mongolian world of the fifteenth century encouraged the adventurism shown by Temur and his ¨ contemporaries. The choices that Temur himself had made also discouraged his successors ¨ from considering further conquest. In the last ten years of his career, he had clearly differentiated between two types of military campaign: those designed to bring land into his domains and those undertaken to display his superiority over rivals. He chose only to incorporate lands which had a strong agricultural base and had been part of the Mongol Empire; these were the regions which would accept his Mongol legitimation and could produce taxes sufficient to support a mixed army of nomad and settled forces. At the time of his death his realm was complete and further conquests would have been both costly and unprofitable. Both Temur and his successors used Mongol legitimation and recognized ¨ their kinship with other Mongol peoples, most notably the Jochid Uzbeks and the eastern Chaghadayid Khanate, from whom they sought brides descended from Chinggis Khan. While Shahrukh discontinued the practice of ruling through a puppet khan, he himself informally adopted the Mongol supreme title of khaghan and in the histories written for him and his sons, the dynasty’s connection to the house of Chinggis Khan became the subject of an elaborate myth. Loyalty to the Mongol heritage did not prevent the Timurids from subscribing fully to the Perso-Islamic culture of their subjects.
Temur¨ himself, though illiterate, was bilingual in Persian and Turkic and had a strong interest in intellectual questions, particularly history and religious studies. He collected at his court not only the finest craftsmen of the cities he conquered, but whatever scholars he could bring home. In religious sciences he was particularly successful; his court contained three scholars of outstanding prestige, Saqd al-Din Taftazani, Sayyid qAli Jurjani, and Muhammad al-Jazari. He commissioned histories of his reign in both Persian and Turkish. What was equally important for the future course of the dynasty was Temur’s active interest in the education of his descendants. ¨ According to the historians of Shahrukh’s period, Temur took charge of the ¨ education of his grandchildren, personally appointing their nurses and tutors. During his lifetime, almost all his grandsons were raised in the central court by Temur’s wives or sometimes those of his followers. They were to be trained ¨ in good behavior, and taught the arts and manners of rulers (ad ab-i padsh ah ı).15
It is clear that cultural patronage was an expected part of rule both for Temur and for his descendants. Shahrukh showed a strong interest in ¨ historical writing and many of Temur’s grandsons were famous for their ¨ enthusiastic and informed patronage. They continued Temur’s interest in ¨ history and religion, and added active patronage of mathematics and astronomy, and most particularly, the arts of the book. The Timurids after Temur excelled not in military might but in cultural ¨ patronage, and this was probably not by chance. While Temur left his heirs a ¨ realm which was logically complete, his cultural legacy provided ample scope for ambition and initiative. His descendants had the advantage of inheriting the Iranian lands ruled by the Mongols, thus the area in which new ideas, techniques and art forms were still in the process of development.
They were in a position to gather the calligraphers and miniature painters of Tabriz and Shiraz and the astronomers working on the rich legacy of Nasir al-Din Tusi, whose observatory at Maragha was financed by the first Ilkhan Huleg ¨ u. The ¨ active exchange of embassies with Ming China, quickly renewed after Temur’s death, continued the importation of outside influences. Thus we ¨ need not be surprised to find that among Temur’s successors, building and ¨ cultural production were among the first steps in the assertion of power and position. Despite significant differences, the Timurids shared many institutions with the neighboring Muslim dynasties of their period. The Ottomans, Delhi sultans, and Mamluks were all Turks, originating from the Eurasian steppe, who ruled over the population as outsiders. Because they owed their prestige to the nomad military prowess of their armies, they preserved the foreign element, whether by upholding traditions and importing new foreign soldiers.
The ‘‘middle period’’ of Islamic history, when rulers of nomad origin predominated, strengthened a number of institutions which were common to the central Islamic lands. While terminology differed among regions, as did the importance of individual institutions, all states in some way used the iqtaq (grants of land use for salary) and charitable waqf endowments, and all struggled with the resultant loss of tax revenue. They endowed similar religious establishments, the madrasa and the khanaq ah , sometimes organized into mausoleum complexes, and thereby created religious positions dependent on their favor. The prestige of Sufi shaykhs and the growing importance of shrines and Sufi brotherhoods was likewise a development common to all regions. Thus we can examine the Timurids as a dynasty trying to control a society similar to that of its neighbors, with many of the same tools. On the other hand, their direct connection to the Mongols and their rule over the central Iranian lands set them apart from Mamluks and Ottomans. We can assume that their society and politics were similar to those of their western neighbors, but significant differences also existed.
The organization of the book One basic premise of this book is that much of the political activity within the realm originated in society, and that the task of the government was less to initiate than to balance and to react. It would be logical therefore to begin my analysis from below, with the city, the countryside and the province. There is one major practical disadvantage to such a course – the narrative history of the period, to which we must refer for our framework, depends largely on the activities of the dynasty and its immediate servitors. Without introduction to the chronology and the personnel of the central government, the history of individual communities cannot be explained or related to each other. I will therefore begin where I would have liked to end, with a discussion of the history of Shahrukh’s reign and the organization of the dynasty, its central army and its formal administration. In the first chapter, I combine a brief narrative history with analysis of the rulers and their Chaghatay followers. My goal is to place events in sequence and show their impact on the dynasty and its core military command. The second chapter is a discussion of the sources and the problems they raise. The third deals with the central chancellery (dıwan ) and its first section is largely narrative. Many of the events introduced in the first and third chapters will be analyzed in greater detail in subsequent chapters concerned with other segments of society.
My fourth chapter is an analysis of the political and military dynamics of Iran, and I have followed it with a discussion of government and society in the province of Fars, since the two chapters deal with similar issues. Chapters 6 and 7 are devoted to the politics of the religious classes; in the sixth chapter I give a general analysis of the dynamics of politics in the religious sphere, and in the seventh discuss specific people, shrines and communities. The last chapter is a description of the rebellion of Shahrukh’s grandson in the last years of his reign and the succession struggle after his death, which illustrate many of the political dynamics discussed throughout the book.
Link
Press Here
0 التعليقات :
إرسال تعليق